Ecco il video dell'incontro in Bocconi, pubblico numeroso e attento, chapeau.
https://www.facebook.com/EcodelBunker/videos/853128048368872/?permPage=1
Presentazione
The European Economic
Constitution (the facto, I am not concerned with the legal aspects)
•
Traditional targets of economic policy: full
employment and price stability (and the equilibrium of the balance of payments)
•
Traditional (macroeconomic) instruments:
monetary policy, fiscal policy (and exchange rate policy)
•
Assignment of instruments to objectives in the
European economic and monetary union (EMU)
•
Monetary policy (independent CB) à price stability
•
Fiscal policy à
neutral (or restrictive bias)
Theoretical background
•
A very rigid version of neoclassical theory
(marginalism). You all know the story:
•
The Phillips curve is vertical in the long-period
(or even in the short). Monetary policy ineffective; independent CB; fiscal
policy crowds out private investment
•
It is better that wet countries tie their hands
leaving monetary policy to a foreign central bank
•
(The experiences of Guido Carli in 1973 when he
declared that the refusal to finance the public debt would have been a
“seditious act”, or when Paolo Baffi opposed the Italian participation to the
EMS, should not be repeated)
•
In this world there is never a problem of AD
(certainly not in the long period). At the “natural interest rate” all savings
are invested.
What is wrong with this
theory?
•
Both in practice and in theory investment does
not depend on the interest rate.
•
Pratice: empirically investment depends on
expected demand (the accelerator) and not on in. Krugman calls it
“the little dirty secret” (in his blog, not in the textbook!)
•
Theory: Sraffa (Piero not Angelo, the son not
the father) initiated the controversy on capital theory (the controversy
between the two Cambridges) that destroyed the foundations of neoclassical
theory. More specifically, the demand functions for “production factors” are
not “well behaved”. This was acknowledged (by the MIT side), and rapidly
forgotten. Any honest scholar would recognize that all that you have studied
(including the labour and capital demand curves, Solow’s model, the
Heckscher-Ohlin theorem, monetarism, DSGE models, Endogenous growth theory,
almost everything you studied) is analytically wrong. But honesty has not
prevailed in Economics, after David Ricardo’s death in 1823, as Marx taught us.
Going back to the theoretical
background to the European economic constitution
•
The central point is that in this view full
employment is a national problem (to be tackled with labour market flexibility)
•
This vision is precisely the opposite to that
which prevailed before the monetarist counter-revolution of the seventies.
•
In the Keynesian view full employment was an
international question.
•
By this view (especially in its long-run, more
genuine, version) output depends on AD. Income distribution matters for
aggregate demand (inequality is an obstacle to growth, as Larry Summers has
lately admitted, acknowledging that PK economist are far ahead in this
respect).
•
Monetary and fiscal policy cooperate to sustain
AD (fiscal dominance). Income policy takes care of inflation (corporativism) ßthis worked
imperfectly in Italy, hence the ill-fated search for an external discipline
•
Controls over capital flows assured a degree of
independence of monetary policy in the Bretton Woods regime.
•
Democracy: elections decide in which point of
the Phillips curve the majority wants to stay
Necessity of an international Keynesianism: why?
•
The balance of payment equilibrium was the main
constraint to national full employment policies. The classical example is the
Mitterand government in the early 1980s. If partners do not cooperate, you
cannot pursue national Keynesian policies.
•
Traditionally, Germany has opposed international
keynesianism
•
Unless: trade controls (not opposed e.g. by
Federico Caffé), or exchange rate flexibility.
•
Prof. Amato à
Keynes’ proposal of an International clearing union that somehow obliged
surplus countries to recycle their surplus (there is a similarity with the
arcane European payment system called Target 2, but this would lead us too far
away).
Germany: the European and
global problem?
•
Since the early 1950s Germany has deliberately
pursued a neo-mercantilist model.
•
Let the others adopt inflationary Keynesians
policies; with fixed exchange rates our exports will take off
•
Rationale à
Michal Kalecki (the Marxist Keynes) à
Profits derives from the capitalists’ surplus (the difference between net
output and wages ß
Ricardo/Sraffa). Lower wages à
higher profit rate, but also, lower wages à
lower domestic demand. Necessity of external markets à government spending,
autonomous consumption, exports.
•
A mercantilist strategy combines wage repression
with high profits in fixed exchange rates regimes (BW, EMS, EMU).
•
Called Monetary mercantilism by the German
leading economic-historian Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich. Violation of game rules of
a MU.
Why did the other countries
accept fixed exchange rate regime with Germany? A few words on Italy
•
Rigid fixed exchange rate regimes are a cap over
social conflict [in this sense inconsistent with democracy (Eichengreen,
Rodrick)]
•
France: the defence of the parity between the FF
and the DM cost a lot in terms of interest rates, so better to proceed with a
full monetary unification
•
In Italy 1979-1981 à change of the monetary regime
(from the ‘permissive’ regime of Carli and Baffi): participation in the EMS,
“divorce” between BdI and the Treasury (plus progressive dismantlement of
capital controls)
•
Consequences: loss of external competitiveness àvictim: public debt
•
3 channels: 1) high interest rates to finance
the BoP gap; 2) lower E and higher M à
lower GDPà
less fiscal revenues; 3) countries with persistent or expanding CA deficits are
often obliged to run fiscal deficits to maintain aggregate demand: ‘Without
fiscal deficit, they will have high unemployment’ (Stiglitz 2010, p. 235)
•
Note that I am reversing the traditional “twin
deficits” hypothesis from the traditional fiscal deficit à CA deficit to CA
deficit à
fiscal deficit
EMU discipline: two components
•
FISCAL DISCIPLINE: Transfer of monetary sovereignty
to a foreign central bank à fiscal discipline à a
government without a central bank is at the mercy of the markets and can
default
•
WAGE DISCIPLINE à
the exchange rate flexibility does not accommodate inflation any more
EMU’s victim: productivity
growth
•
Labour productivity depends on AD (“the division
of labour depends on the extent of the market”, Kaldor-Verdoon law, economies
of scale and investment depend on AD)
•
From 1995 on the Italian economic policy has
been more consistent and fiscal policy more conservative. The external
competitiveness regained in 1992 was slowly eroded. Both factors might explain
the stagnation of labour productivity from 1995.
Fixed exchange rate regimes as heralds of financial
crises
•
Apart from Paul DeGrauwe who in an article on
the FT envisaged a construction bubble in Spain, fuelled by capital inflows,
followed by a BoP crisis, nobody foresaw that the EMU might incur an internal
BoP crisis. Note that Giavazzi and Baldwin arrived at this obvious
interpretation with years of delay.
•
Incomplete monetary union generates financial
crisis (indebtedness of the periphery, sudden stop of capital flows, default).
In Europe the financial (BoP) crisis did not explode because of TARGET 2 (Sinn)
and the delayed ECB intervention (whatever it takes, OMT). Very complicated
story.
•
Of course you do not meet BoP crises in the US.
This leads us to the basic flaws of the EMU: the US are a complete, viable
monetary union, the EMU is not (and will never be).
Deflationary bias in an incomplete monetary union (MU)
with no political union (and with the dominant country refusing to exercise
leadership)
•
Mundell (1961) with Germany in mind à a monetary union in a
non-OCA would lead to competitiveness shocks in the periphery and to the
refusal of core country to expand à
deflationary bias
•
In a full, viable MU a federal budget (assisted
by a cooperative CB) operates fiscal transfers and anti-cyclical policies. Full
financial integration and a full banking union avoid a doom loop between local
banks and governments.
•
In a viable MU the fiscal parameters on national
budgets make sense
•
A full, viable MU implies a political union.
Barba & De Vivo: federal budget irrelevant in the
eurozone
Is a federal, progressive Europe possible? Next question,
please.
•
Hayek 1939: the opposition of core countries to
a tax-transfer union implies that only a liberal (ordoliberal as by now
everybody has learned to say) Europe is possible.
•
Europe is the Mecca of the liberals (in the
European sense), and not of the liberals (in the American sense).
•
The nation-State is the traditional arena of the
social conflict (that is of democracy) over income distribution (direct and
indirect wages) and economic policy.
•
Supra-national institutions humiliate national
democracies (that ordinary people is incapable of taking care of themselves is
openly declared by the most honest pro-Europeans, and of course by mainstream
economists).
•
International cooperation between sovereign
democracies is not synonym of sinister nationalism (this is an odious
accusation)
Reforms
•
Macron’s proposed reforms of the EZ were very
timid (much fanfare about nothing)à
a tiny federal budget
•
Germany said no. The German interpretation of
the crisis is that too little and not too much discipline characterised Europe.
•
So the German proposals aim to remove the
control over national budgets from the Commission (too political bargaining)
and assign it to technocratic authorities like the EMF.
•
The rest of the proposals are just financial
engineering (once the Eurobonds are taken off the table)
What could realistically Italy fight for? Conclusions
Ddt
= (rt – gt) dt-1 - st
•
where d is the public debt/GDP ratio,
r is the average nominal interest rate paid on the public debt, g is
the nominal growth rate, and s is the primary balance/GDP ratio.
•
The past decades have seen various combinations
of these variables. This graph is from a paper I co-authored with Gennaro Zezza
(Levy Institute and Unicass)
What could Italy fight for? Conclusions
•
Since long ago (Appellodeglieconomisti 2010)
some economists proposed a stabilization of the Italian Public debt/GDP ratio
(I hope we all agree that there is not any magic number for this ratio)
•
With a sufficiently low interest rate (lower
than the growth rate) the stabilization is consistent with a primary fiscal
deficit, that is a moderate expansionary fiscal stance.
•
A similar proposal from Folkerts-Landau (chief
economist of the DB): a grand bargain between Italy and Europe comprised of low
interest rates and support for Italian growth in exchange of a firm commitment
to fiscal stabilization.
•
Current situation r > g, s > 0. We need g
> r and s < 0 (we also need a German-led recovery to avoid BoP problems à but Berlin refuses to
expand).
What could (realistically) Italy fight for? Conclusions
•
In my view, it would be unacceptable for Italy
to implement this on the terms proposed by Folkerts-Landau, i.e. through an
application of the ECB's Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) accompanied by a
memorandum of understanding and an intervention of the European Stability
Mechanism (ESM). But an honourable solution could be found.
•
The question is the lack of credibility of the
last governments in Italy (all prime ministers included) and the lack of will
(and economic ignorance) on the European (read, German) side.
Euroexit?
•
The question might become actual again in case a
new financial crisis with the spread going up.
•
3 problems:
•
Gross foreign debt denominated in euro
•
Possible ouster from Target 2 (in principle also
non-€ countries use Target 2) à
possible retaliation
•
Other trade retaliations
•
Better to avoid it. Yes, of course.
•
Hopes in a change of Europe? None
•
Internal change of Italy à there will be no
institutional change (in a wide sense) without growth
Suggested readings (from where you can collect further
references)
•
On the Classical surplus approach, the
criticism to neoclassical theory and Keynes:
Cesaratto, S. (2019) The modern revival of the Classical
surplus approach: implications for the analysis of growth and crises, in T.
Gabellini, S.Gasperin, A. Moneta (eds.) Economic Crisis and Economic
Thought – Alternative theoretical perspectives on the economic crisis,
Routledge, Abingdon & New York, pp. 111-134. WP version:
https://ideas.repec.org/p/usi/wpaper/735.html
•
On the EMU:
Cesaratto, S. (2017) Alternative Interpretations of a
Stateless Currency crisis, Cambridge Journal of Economics, Volume
41, Issue 4, July 2017, Pages 977–998, free download:
https://academic.oup.com/cje/article/41/4/977/2964673
Cesaratto, S. (2018), The nature of the eurocrisis. A
reply to Febrero, Uxò and Bermejo, Review of Keynesian Economics,
Vol. 6 No. 2, Summer 2018, pp. 240–251 (working paper version Quaderni
DEPS n. 752).
•
On Italy and Europe
Cesaratto, S., & Zezza, G. (2019). What went wrong with
Italy, and what the country should now fight for in Europe. in H.Hansjorg,
J.Priewe&A.Watt (a cura di), Still Time to save the Euro, Berlin:
Social Europe Publishing.
https://www.socialeurope.eu/book/still-time-to-save-the-euro
Cesaratto, S. Italy: A Question of Interest Rates and
Trust (Editorial), Intereconomics, Volume 53, November/December 2018,
Number 6. https://archive.intereconomics.eu/year/2018/6/italy-a-question-of-interest-rates-and-trust/
Servaas Storm,
(2019) How to Ruin a Country in Three Decades, https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/how-to-ruin-a-country-in-three-decades?fbclid=IwAR17WzDWXFzngSwtA__43A1_YjtGJU2U248lE7CIzYIdBiep_FmyzYGKXBI
In Italian
S.Cesaratto
(2016) Sei lezioni di economia - Conoscenze necessarie per capire la crisi
più lunga (e come uscirne), Imprimatur editore,3a ristampa*
Cesaratto, S.
(2018), Chi non rispetta le regole? Italia e Germania, le doppie morali
dell'euro , Imprimatur, Reggio Emilia.*
Sergio Cesaratto
& Gennaro Zezza, 2018. "Farsi male da soli: Disciplina esterna, domanda
aggregata e il declino economico italiano," WorkingPapers 2018-05, Universita' di Cassino, Dipartimento di Economia e Giurisprudenza
(forthcoming in L’industria in a special number in memory of Marcello De
Cecco).
* Unfortunately the publisher has closed. A new edition of
the best-selling Sei lezioni should be published next autumn with a new
publisher .
Contacts
•
sergio.cesaratto@unisi.it
•
https://docenti.unisi.it/it/sergiocesaratto
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento